0

Cracked recent Publications - Molecular & Genetic Epidemiology Group

Other operating systems and browsers that include complete implementations of ECMAScript edition 3 and CSS 2.0 may work, but are not. Fire emblem 7 hacks. Jump to: navigation, searchnavigation, search. Firefox 58 also builds on last Fall's release of. Audiophile for mac os. The latest crack was Me spore patch, fixes a crash in the Building Creator when holding Ctrl or Shift and moving a part. On this page you can download patches that provide support for the Firefox versions, which are not supported by the TestComplete version you are using.

Key generator online Essay Help - Get your assignment help services from

Recap/Steven Universe Future S 1 E 5 Bluebird Recap/Supernatural S 05 E 19 Hammer Of The Gods Recap/Teenange Mutant Ninja Turtles 2020 S 5 E 4 Moreworlds Than One. You are able to simulate the creation and evolution of a creature from a single cell organism, to a dangerous beast if that's what you wish. File name Downloads Added; [HOST]. Pool live tour coins hack software. When taking photos, remember that the image is top-bottom reversed in the camera, so if the film is sitting along the bottom of the plate, it will expose the top of the image you see in the view-finder. Metal storm hack no jailbreak ifunbox classic.

1

Patch dict_files/en_US.dic - PHP Sentence Parser - PHP Classes

Patch is now available on Steam. Two things are worth noting. David Foster Wallace was born in Ithaca, New York, in 1962 and raised in Illinois, where he was a regionally ranked junior tennis player. Game crysis 3 full crack. Find all the latest Spore PC game downloads on [HOST]. Tranquil Boots Movement speed increased from 85 to 90 HP. Spore: Galactic Adventures - Take Your Creature From Zero To Galactic Hero Get out of your.

  • Fountain Essays - Just another WordPress site
  • LiveJournal: Discover global communities of bloggers who
  • Program Publications: University of California-Davis
  • C. T. Bauer College of Business at the University of Houston
  • Download Spore Patch 6 Changelog free
  • Reach Expats - Advertise to the Expat Market
  • September 2020 - Overclockers Australia
2
  • Education Development Center
  • English/1001 Motivational Quotes for Success Great Quotes
  • MIT - Massachusetts Institute of Technology
  • HOW TO HACK photos on Flickr
  • The Pale King by David Foster Wallace, Paperback
  • Unicorn Bags - Cultivation - Stropharia rugoso-annulata
  • Links 18/6/2020: Linux 5.2 RC5 and OpenMandriva Lx 4
  • Everything At One Click: December 2020
  • View source for User: C5mml8yytt - Public Records
  • FIFA 20 Crack PC All Torrent Full Game Free Download [2020]

Expat Dating in Germany - chatting and dating - Front page DE

Hari Mohan Prasad rightly holds the view that the confessional cast of the novel. Topics Replies Author Views Last Posts; Big Whoop: PS3 Firmware 2.43 Released: 0: Admin: 2910. Key english test for schools 1 navigate to this site. Photography Gallery Sunday, 28-September-2020 19: 30: 05 (GMT +10) - by DiGiTaL MoNkEY: Some recent. Tropico 4 modern times product key. Please update your bookmarks and visit [HOST] from now on.

3
  • Apple Daily News – 2020-05-26 – STATOPERATOR
  • Crypto Help: { bitcoin machine in france }
  • Molecular & Genetic Epidemiology Group - Selected Publications
  • Apache2 Ubuntu Default Page: It works
  • Marvelous Things Overheard: Poems by Ange Mlinko
  • Course Content - #94923: Animal-Related Health Risks
  • Src/public/js/zxcvbn.js - CMS Airship - PHP Classes
  • Glass Wings Blog: Subject Index
  • Person Details: Bruce D. Hammock (Superfund Research Program)
  • Libery Newsprint Nov-6-09 Edition by Liberty Newspost

Safe Exam Browser / SVN / [r3221] /tags/win/1.5/Seb

You should make the hidden Grox parts. See File Details for a list of changes and fixes. BULL'S EYE: We've finally found the name of one of the chemicals slime molds use to communicate with one another. This is what it should look like inside the Electronic Arts folder. Asymmetry: 20 May 2020: Ancient grease: 26 Jun 2020: MotoGP report: 18 Jul 2020: Missing links: 26 Jul 2020: Spot the bike: 1 Aug 2020: Helpful hands: 23 Aug 2020: In a hurry: 5 Sep 2020: Workers of the web untie: 17 Sep 2020: Mobilisation: 24 Sep 2020: Seeing stars: 3 Oct 2020: Cache my drift: 16 Oct 2020: Zero hour. Reloaded no CD Spore v All.

4

Potassium chloride, 7447-40-7

Spore patch 5 asymmetry firefox. For my ENTIRE list of Spore mods, addons and enhancements, plus.

Dr Johnny Ryan of Brave & Dr Orla Lynskey of the London School of Economics make a submission to the UK Competition & Markets Authority outlining significant digital market problems

Dr Johnny Ryan of Brave & Dr Orla Lynskey of the London School of Economics make a submission to the UK Competition & Markets Authority outlining significant digital market problems

Competition issues in digital markets

See full blog post here: http://brave.com/uk-cma/
This note presents a submission from Dr Johnny Ryan of Brave, and Dr Orla Lynskey of the London School of Economics, to the UK Competition & Markets Authority.
The UK Government Competition & Markets Authority (CMA) is examining online platforms and digital advertising market. Dr. Johnny Ryan of Brave, and Dr Orla Lynskey of the London School of Economics have made a submission to the CMA that outlines significant market problems.
The submission to the CMA outlines a number of significant problems.
Dominant digital companies use their position of market power to create “cascading monopolies”. They do this in part by cross-using data for purposes beyond what the data were initially collected for. This offensive leveraging of data avoids the need to compete in each new domain on the merits.
These firms also use their position to extract amounts of data from individuals beyond what might be considered a fair or reasonable exchange. The digital industry’s data excess norm is similar to the banking industry’s credit excess norm that precipitated the financial crisis. It incentivises a shadow economy based on unnecessary and insecure data processing.
Dominant firms merit particular attention because (a) they shape the markets, and (b) the implications of their actions are felt most acutely by those dependent on them. This is why they have a ‘special responsibility’ in competition law, and should also have a ‘special responsibility’ in a risk-based data protection law too.
Regulators can correct anticompetitive data advantage without breaking up a company. By acting against unfair conflation of purposes that should be separate, data protection authorities can force incumbents to compete in each new line of business on the merits alone, rather than on the basis of leveraged data accrued by virtue of their dominance in other lines of business. For large digital firms with many distinct services, which may be tied or presented as a suite, this may be a powerful tool to prevent them from shutting down competition.
The submission also discusses the problem of monopsony/cartel practices in the “real-time bidding” (RTB) online advertising market, which disadvantages publishers. The RTB system commodifies publisher’s own particular audiences, undercutting their business. It also extracts enormous – and generally opaque – percentages for adtech intermediaries.
In addition, consumer harm is caused when advertising spending is diverted from content producing publishers to criminal fraudsters, to the “bottom of the web”, and to platforms that do not contribute content. The result appears to be a reduction in choice of quality content.
The full text of the submission is copied below, and can be downloaded from the UK CMA website.
Online Platforms TeamCompetition & Markets AuthorityVictoria HouseSouthampton RowLondon WC1B 4ADUnited Kingdom
Online platforms and digital advertising market study
Dear Colleague,
  1. We welcome the opportunity to comment on the CMA’s market study of online platforms and digital advertising. We have professional and personal interests in this study.
- Dr Ryan represents Brave, a rapidly growing Internet browser based in San Francisco and London, co-founded by Brendan Eich, the inventor of JavaScript and co-founder of Mozilla/Firefox.
- Dr Lynskey is an Associate Professor at LSE, working in the areas of data protection and technology regulation. Dr Lynksey is an editor of International Data Privacy Law (OUP) and a member of the European Commission’s GDPR Expert Stakeholder Group. She has previously worked in Competition Law practice in Brussels.
We respond to the three themes defined in the CMA’s statement of scope in turn, with reference to our previous work and expertise where relevant.
  1. Data is power. Data is both a potential source of market power and is a source of power over individuals. As such, the control over and processing of personal data by undertakings is a matter that is relevant to multiple regulators and regulatory frameworks, including competition law, data protection law and consumer protection law. The issues raised are thus both substantive and institutional.
  2. From a substantive perspective, intermediary platforms occupy a strategic place in the online environment, putting them in a privileged position to collect and process personal data across a wide variety of content and services. When these intermediaries are dominant, they are able to exploit this privileged position by extracting excessive personal data in exchange for the use of their platform. Moreover, many of the ‘behind the scenes’ practices which these platforms provide an economic incentive for – most notably, online advertising and the real-time bidding process – operate in their shadow. As regulators cannot see this shadow economy, they have difficulties regulating it.
  3. From an institutional perspective, it is critical that regulators collaborate to avoid unnecessary duplication and ensure consistency and coherence in the policies they pursue and in how they interpret and apply relevant legal frameworks.
Theme 1 The market power of online platforms in consumer-facing markets
The Factors Leading to Market Power
  1. The factors that lead to market dominance in a given market are multi-faceted. Digital markets are no different.
  2. While dominant companies, such as Facebook, maintain a strong proprietary claim over the personal data they process (for instance, by collecting data regarding user activity from webpages with embedded Facebook plug-ins but not sharing this data), it is often claimed that personal data is not itself a barrier to entry to digital markets. Rather, it is asserted that it is what is done with the personal data – the algorithm that it is applied to it, for example – that is decisive in obtaining a competitive advantage through data. We acknowledge that whether personal data is a barrier to entry is an empirical question that must be subject to a context specific assessment. In making this assessment, we concur with the German and French competition authorities that the volume of data alone is not decisive and that an assessment of the ‘quantity and quality of the established company’s data set’ is required.[1]
  3. Beyond control over data, it is possible to identify several factors that contribute to dominance in the online environment: direct and indirect network effects; a permissive competition framework, permissive oversight of data-driven mergers and acquisitions; commercial data-agreements between dominant undertakings and other parties enabling data-sharing; and a flexible data protection framework with weak enforcement mechanisms.[2]
  4. The example of Facebook will illustrate how these factors can be brought to bear in order to consolidate the market power of a digital platform. First, we could say that network effects have played a significant role in Facebook’s success as a platform and in the failure of would-be competitor platforms. Facebook now has over 2 billion active users with no sign of a viable competitor on the horizon. Put simply, this is because consumers want their social networking service to be social: it is critical for consumers that their friends and family also use the platform. This direct network effect can lead to indirect network effects: advertisers will be attracted to the Facebook platform for advertising given the large number of active users it has attracted and its potential to mine its data to profile these users for targeted advertising purposes.
  5. Facebook has further consolidated this market power, through a series of data-driven acquisitions, the most notable of which being its acquisition of potential competitors Instagram and Whatsapp as well as Onavo. The latter was a virtual private network (VPN) which enabled Facebook to gain a strategic oversight of how its users were using other mobile phone applications.[3] Although the European Commission examined the Whatsapp merger and granted it merger clearance, the commercial rationale for Facebook’s acquisition of Whatsapp – the acquisition of Whatsapp user data – fell in the blind spot of the Commission’s analysis.[4] Furthermore, the implications of the transaction from a data protection perspective, were entirely overlooked by the Commission, which delegated this issue to data protection law.
  6. This is unfortunate as the strain on the data protection regime brought about by ubiquitous data processing and a weak data protection framework has itself contributed to the dominance of Facebook. The entry into force of the General Data Protection Regulation (GDPR) is likely to improve the effectiveness of the framework, in particular from an enforcement perspective.[5] Yet, as the market’s response to the recently announced USD5 billion fine for Facebook indicates, given its high turnover and the centrality of personal data processing to its operations, a concerted and consistent approach to its legal compliance is required.
Cascading Monopolies and the Leveraging of Market Power in Data-Driven Markets
  1. We believe that dominant digital companies use their position of market power as intermediaries to create cascading monopolies.
  2. The leveraging of market power from one digital market to another through a combination of the mechanisms mentioned above – acquisitions; network effects; weak data protection enforcement – is evident in the following example.
EXAMPLE: GOOGLE, A DATA GRAB?
Google operates over eighty services. Until 2012, Google held these data in distinct silos. In 2012, Google pooled the data it processed about individuals across its services. As a result, this integrated data set enabled Google Shopping, for instance, to use data collected on YouTube or other Google services to offer advertisements to individuals.
Separately, Google acquired a large advertising technology firm called DoubleClick in April 2007. DoubleClick builds up profiles about what people do online in order to define for advertisers what people should see which advertising. When Google bought DoubleClick, it promised to never combine Google users’ personal data from Gmail, YouTube and other accounts with DoubleClick’s data about them. In June 2016 Google went back on that promise, combining personal data about every online individual from its DoubleClick business and all other Google businesses. DoubleClick is active on 8.4 million websites,****[6] which means that its data concerns every single person in the UK.
Indeed, Google was already acquiring one company per week in 2011, thereby increasing the volume and variety of the data it amassed.****[7]
It also entered into strategic agreements involving data sharing with one such example being a partnership between Deepmind (held by Alphabet, Google’s parent company) and the NHS Royal Free Trust in London. This partnership saw the NHS Trust hand over the data of 1.6 million patients of the Trust without their consent and without a commitment on Deepmind’s part to separate this data from that held by its parent company.****[8]
Finally, in September 2018, Google modified its “Chrome” web browser so that users would automatically be signed in to the browser when they use any individual Google service. In other words, it was no longer possible to use Chrome without being signed in to the browser once one signed in to Gmail, or any other Google product. Google did not announce this change.
  1. In this example, Google acts as a cascading monopoly, leveraging its power from one market to the next in a way that actively circumvents individual control over personal data.
  2. It may be argued that such practices are not unique to dominant digital firms, and this is undoubtedly true. Yet, as competition experts are aware, the actions of dominant firms merit particular attention because (a) these firms shape the markets on which they operate and (b) the implications of their actions are felt most acutely by all those dependent on them. Indeed, it is for this reason that these firms have a ‘special responsibility’ in competition law[9] and should also have a ‘special responsibility’ when it comes to respecting the rights of individuals.[10]
  3. As outlined briefly below, the actions of dominant digital firms militate against effective data protection regulation. We wish to highlight two aspects of this tension.
  4. First, not only do the actions of dominant companies render individual control over personal data virtually impossible, they also unsettle established data protection principles designed to ensure the collective benefits of data protection. This aspect is often overlooked in competition reports, which focus on perfecting individual control over data and thus ensuring efficient data markets. Second, dominant firms have created a norm of data excess, in much the same way as banks created a norm of credit excess prior to the financial crisis. This norm in turn incentivises a shadow economy based on unnecessary and insecure data processing (which is beyond the scope of this note).
Theme 2 Consumer control over data collection practices
Individual Control over Personal Data and its Data Protection Limits
  1. While much of the focus in the statement of scope is on the mechanisms of ‘consent’ and ‘transparency’ in data protection law, it is imperative to recall that while data protection law seeks to give individuals control over personal data, this control is not absolute, nor should it be.[11] Individual control over personal data is, in some instances, neither a necessary nor a sufficient aspect of the data protection framework. Indeed, attempts to create a framework based entirely on such individual control would be tantamount to creating a property right in personal data, and a market for such data, a route which data protection law in Europe deliberately eschews.
  2. Rather, the objectives served by data protection – as with other fundamental rights such as freedom of expression – are both individual and collective. The legal framework therefore strikes a balance between competing rights and interests. It recognises situations where individual consent is not necessary and principles that must be respected irrespective of individual consent.[12] Two such principles – particularly relevant in the context of online data processing – are purpose limitation and data minimisation.
  3. Purpose limitation ring fences the personal data processed by undertakings.[13] According to this principle, personal data can only be processed for ‘specified, explicit and legitimate purposes and not further processed in a manner that is incompatible with these purposes’. Further regulatory guidance on this principle has been provided by European data protection authorities in 2013. The then ‘Article 29 Working Party’ advised that a purpose must be “sufficiently defined to enable the implementation of any necessary data protection safeguards,” and must be “sufficiently unambiguous and clearly expressed.”[14] The objective of this test was to ensure that ‘individuals will know what to expect’ and to prevent ‘unanticipated uses’ by the controller or third parties of the data.[15]
  4. Consider for example the act of posting a photo on a hypothetical social media service for the first time. The distinct processing purposes involved might be something like the following list. The person posting the photo is only interested in the first four or five of these purposes:
To display your posts on your feed.
To display posts on tagged friends’ feeds.
To display friends posts that tag you on your feed.
To identify untagged people in your posts.
To record your reaction to posts to refine future content for you, which may include ethnicity, politics, sexuality, etc…, to make our feed more relevant to you.
To record your reaction to posts to refine future content for you, which may include ethnicity, politics, sexuality, etc…, to make ads relevant to you.
To record your reaction to posts to refine future content for you, which may include ethnicity, politics, sexuality, etc…, for advertising fraud prevention.
If a company were to rely on consent, for example, then consent must be requested in a granular manner for each “specified, explicit” data processing purpose. In other words, consent cannot be bundled, as an Advocate General of the Court of Justice of the EU has recently affirmed.[16]
  1. In the Working Party guidelines on consent, European Data Protection Authorities observed that:
“data subjects should be free to choose which purpose they accept, rather than having to consent to a bundle of processing purposes … If the controller has conflated several purposes for processing and has not attempted to seek separate consent for each purpose, there is a lack of freedom. This granularity is closely related to the need of consent to be specific …. When data processing is done in pursuit of several purposes, the solution to comply with the conditions for valid consent lies in granularity, i.e. the separation of these purposes and obtaining consent for each purpose.” [17]
  1. If we return to the example above of the Google ‘Single Sign-In’ for Chrome browser users, it is unlikely it would meet the standard of ‘predictability’ or the requirement that information be presented to individuals in an accessible and unbundled format. Following outcry about this new mechanism, rather than reversing the change, Google added a way for users to deactivate the automatic sign-in. However, this was buried in an ‘Advanced’ settings menu.
  2. Thus, it is clear that any focus on simply ensuring ‘notice and choice’ for consumers in data-driven markets will ignore the broader remit and potential impact of data protection law. The effective enforcement of principles such as purpose limitation by data protection authorities will have consequences for digital competition. If undertakings are actually required to have a separate legal basis for each data processing operation they undertaking, and this purpose must be legitimate and predictable, then this could lead to a ‘soft’ break-up of dominant digital firms. Prohibiting the unlawful conflation of personal data would force incumbents to compete in each new line of business on the merits alone, rather than to allow their strategic market position to cascade across markets as currently occurs. This is therefore a matter for regulatory co-operation, as we describe later.
  3. Finally, it is worth reiterating that to the extent that data protection law does seek to facilitate individual control over personal data in the digital environment, the limits of such control are apparent to any user of the Internet. Dominant digital companies are alive to the threat of regulation, in particular in the aftermath of data scandals like Cambridge Analytica. The market has therefore responded to calls for individual control over personal data by introducing tools such as data dashboards. However, such tools over inadequate control.[18] Even if they provided consumers with robust control, this would only cover what ‘frontstage’. However, what is happening backstage – such as the processing of personal data in the context of the real-time bidding process described below– remains impossible for users to control.
Data Glut: The Extraction of Excess Personal Data
  1. Players with a position of market power in data-driven markets can use this position to extract quantities of data from individuals in excess of that which would be predicted or predictable by consumers, or might be considered a fair or reasonable exchange. This is both a competition law issue and a data protection issue.
  2. It is a data protection issue in at least two ways. First, ‘data minimisation’ is a core principle of data protection. The GDPR provides that personal data shall be ‘adequate, relevant and limited to what is necessary in relation to the purposes for which they are processed’.[19] This requires undertakings to store and process only the minimum quantity of data necessary for their purposes. At present, dominant companies are trying to have their cake and eat it. On the one hand they claim that the vast volume and variety of data they process is of little utility and does not itself confer a competitive advantage on them. On the other hand, if this data is not necessary for their commercial purposes, data protection regulators may query on what basis it is processed. In other words, it is unlikely that data lacks commercial utility for competition law purposes and can satisfy ‘data minimisation’ for data protection purposes.
  3. A second way in which data protection law can examine the volume and variety of data extracted from an individual is when the performance of a contract is made conditional on the extraction of that data. An undertaking must have a legal basis or justification to engage in lawful data processing. If this justification is the performance of a contract, then the data processed must in fact be ‘necessary’ for the performance of this contract. Alternatively, if the legal justification is ‘consent’, but the contract will not be performed unless the individual consents to unnecessary processing, then it is likely this consent will not be ‘freely given’ and therefore lawful. It follows that in data protection law, it is crucial to consider whether the data processing is ‘necessary’.
  4. ‘Necessity’ in data protection law has been construed narrowly, in recognition of the power and information asymmetries between individuals and those who process their personal data. Courts and regulators have yet to issue decisive guidance on whether some data monetisation is appropriate in the context of contracts that are provided for ‘free’ at the point of access (such as Facebook’s social networking service). The European Data Protection Supervisor highlights the limits imposed on such monetisation as a result of data protection’s fundamental rights character .[20] An advisor to the Court of Justice has suggested that some monetisation is appropriate, noting however that this monetisation should be necessary for the performance of the contract.[21] However, even if such a transaction were to be authorised, the volume, variety and sensitivity of data derived from the usage of the ‘free’ services of dominant platforms is excessive. At a minimum, dominant companies should be required to lay bare to regulators how much data they process for a typical user, the value they derive from this data and how this relates to the cost of the service provision. Indeed, the transparency principle of the GDPR appears to require them to do this.[22]
  5. In addition, data protection law requires that processing be fair[23] and proportionate.[24] If the minimisation and necessity tests are failed, the fairness and proportionality tests are too.
  6. An analogy might be drawn between the assessment required of data protection authorities in this context to determine how much data it is reasonable to extract from individuals in such circumstances and the assessments competition authorities make in excessive pricing cases. Indeed, this issue could be viewed from a competition perspective by querying whether excessive data collection whether directly or via third party trackers could constitute a form of excessive pricing.[25]
Theme 3 Competition in the supply of digital advertising in the UK
  1. There are several market problems that disadvantage publishers and foreclose innovative entrants. First, cross-usage of data by dominant players creates barriers to entry to innovative market entrants. This is described in the discussion about theme 1, above.
  2. Second, monopsony/cartel practices in the “real-time bidding” online advertising market disadvantage publishers. Publishers lose their ability to monetize their unique audience, and pay enormous – and generally opaque – percentages to distribution intermediaries when selling ad space.
Overview of market problems in real-time bidding market
http://preview.redd.it/jc1rh35bp6r31.png?width=974&format;=png&auto;=webp&s;=16753d2e240a6a8b05ff5e29ebe4948e2ef8ec6d
In this market, publishers of websites and apps supply the online audience who view advertising. Marketers, who pay for advertisements to be shown to this audience, are the buyers. Advertising technology companies such as “real-time bidding ad exchanges” are the distributors.
  1. We are concerned by the degree to which concentration in the adtech sector, which controls distribution, may have created a monopsony or cartel situation, where publishers who supply advertising views are compelled to do business with a small number of highly concentrated real-time bidding advertising exchanges and systems that purchase or facilitate the purchase of their advertising space, and dictate terms. The table below shows the scale, in numbers of transactions (bid requests) per day, of the seven largest RTB advertising exchanges.
RTB exchanges: bid requests per day
  1. As the table shows, Google is by far the dominant participant in the market. We are concerned that publishers may be required to agree to practices such as the use of unique identifiers in RTB “bid requests” that enable companies that receive these to turn each publishers’ unique audience into a commodity that can be targeted on cheaper sites and apps. In addition to the data protection implications of such practices, this strips a reputable publisher of their most essential asset.
  2. We are also concerned about the degree to which “adtech” firms that control the distribution of the advertising slots supplied by web site publishers have distorted the market. 70%-55% of advertising revenue now goes to distribution “adtech” firms.[33]
  3. Third, consumer harm is caused when advertising spending is diverted from content producing publishers to criminal fraudsters, the bottom of the web, and platforms that do not contribute content. The result appears to be a reduction in choice of quality content.
  4. Fourth, publishers of websites and apps have their audiences commodified and arbitraged on low-rent sites, and suffer further from the diversion of revenue away from their sites to fake sites by ad fraud scammers. This is described in a section below.
Lack of transparency & inefficiency: ad fraud
  1. Because of the opacity of the online advertising market, advertisers do not know whether the people viewing their ads are humans or software “bots” masquerading as people to fraudulently extract money from the advertiser.
  2. Juniper Research estimates that ad fraud will divert $42 billion of advertisers’ spending to criminals in 2019, globally.[34] The US Association of National Advertisers estimates that at least $5.8 billion of their expenditure is wasted on ad fraud. [35]
  3. Facebook 3 billion fake accounts in early 2019, and 1.3 billion fake accounts the year before.[36] (Facebook has only 2.4 billion users in a typical month). The enormous scale of the fraud problem makes it clear how inefficient the market is, and how little reporting received by a digital advertiser is reliable.
Lack of transparency & inefficiency: audience arbitrage
  1. Recent research concluded that RTB increases publisher revenue by a mere 4 percent.[37] We believe that the reality is worse for publishers than this report suggests. This is because the study does not take account of two large costs that publishers bear: first, their audiences are commodified and arbitraged, and second, ad fraud diverts billions of dollars of advertising spending from their websites and in to the hands of criminals. The diagram below shows how these problems occur.
Audience arbitrage: how worthy publishers’ audiences are commodified.
http://preview.redd.it/ggvzqxthp6r31.png?width=974&format;=png&auto;=webp&s;=0fddaa7e450745983399aa6d460988133aae23b3
  1. While The Daily Bugle may net £1 the first time this occurs, it finds itself undercut by De5troyTru5t.com thereafter. Thus, the online real-time bidding advertising system commodifies worthy publishers’ unique audiences, and enables a business model for the bottom of the Web.
Example of an ad fraud scam: fake traffic bought by scam-publishers.
http://preview.redd.it/41rtm7wkp6r31.png?width=974&format;=png&auto;=webp&s;=2e37e3290b6d87a2671d350fc8df7980ddeffc8e
  1. We believe that the current model of “broadcast behavioural” harms publishers. The way to solve this is to pressure the two standard-setting organizations that control the market: the IAB and Google, to remove personal data that enable audience arbitrage and much of the “bot fraud” problem from the system. This would also stop the real-time bidding from leakage of sensitive, profiling data about every single web user. Currently profiling data about web users is leaked in hundreds of billions of broadcasts every day.[38]
  2. Making this transition change at the industry standards level that affects everybody avoids individual companies facing a first mover disadvantage if they act alone. This is why it is essential that the relevant regulator acts to ban the broadcasting of personal data at the industry specification level, banning the IAB and Google from permitting personal data fields to be included in RTB bid requests.
  3. We anticipate that a market in which all publishers make the same transition will yield far higher revenues to publishers. However, we also understand that for most publishers this is impossible to do alone. There is a first mover disadvantage, or prisoner’s dilemma: one publisher is not able to make the first move on its own for fear that its competitors will not follow suit. It will then be at a market disadvantage in the short and medium term, and may not be able to enjoy the benefit of the transition to clean data in the long term.
  4. The likelihood is that publishers can only enjoy this benefit if they move together. And this can only happen if the two IAB and Google real-time bidding industry standards is changed, causing the transition to apply to all publishers at the same moment.
An Institutional Perspective: Filling the Regulatory Gaps
  1. There is the potential for competition law and policy in this area to be both internally and externally inconsistent. This internal inconsistency could, for instance, be claimed where – on the one hand – competition authorities permit data-driven acquisitions without imposing limits on the subsequent pooling of data across the merged entity while – on the other hand – later considering options to mitigate this data power through mechanisms such as data sharing.
  2. There is also a danger of external inconsistency: for instance, it may be that both of these options, in fact, undermine individual control over personal data and undermine the legal framework for personal data processing. For instance, proposed data sharing or interoperability proposals would need to be closely examined in order to assess their compliance with purpose limitation. Moreover, even if the data sharing or interoperability served the same purpose, it may nevertheless be incompatible with the principle of fairness. A user may be happy to have their personal data processed by one provider for medical research purposes (eg the NHS) but not by another (eg. Google’s Deepmind).
  3. Competition law and data protection law should be working in tandem in digital markets, rather than pulling in opposite directions. Concrete proposals to facilitate such cooperation have been made by the European Data Protection Supervisor at EU level: such regulatory cooperation would also benefit the UK.
  4. In particular, competition and data protection authorities should together consider whether there is adequate enforcement of the purpose limitation principle. Purpose specification protects a consumer’s opportunity to choose what to opt-in to, and forbids a company from automatically opt-ing a person in to all of its services and tracking. The unfair conflation of data purposes, and cross-use of data, make it impossible for consumers to make informed choices, and expose sensitive information about them, such as their location and private browsing habits, that can disadvantage them in several important respects including fraud, invasion of privacy, disclosure of sensitive information about them in a breach or otherwise, erosion of trust, weakened bargaining position, manipulation, and ultimately a limit of the choice available to them in the market as a result of offensive leveraging of personal information.
  5. A complex business that relies on data to operate can be analyzed by itemizing the following, for every data processing purpose: the specific purpose, the personal information it applies to, and the legal justification of the use of that personal information for that specific purpose. Provided a granular definition of purpose is adopted, this is a forensic method to build a detailed understanding of complex digital firms’ operations. It also enables an examiner to determine whether the use of particular data for particular purposes is permissible, and if personal information is being cross-used and offensively leveraged. This is important, because the cross-use of data is a serious antitrust concern. Young, innovative companies can be snuffed by giant incumbents who erect barriers to entry by cross-using data for purposes beyond what they were initially collected for.
  6. Regulators can correct anticompetitive data advantage without breaking up a company. By acting against unfair conflation of purposes that should be separate, data protection authorities can force incumbents to compete in each new line of business on the merits alone, rather than on the basis of leveraged data accrued by virtue of their dominance in other lines of business. For large digital firms with many distinct services, which may by tied or presented as a suite, this may be a powerful tool to prevent them from shutting down competition.
  7. Finally, one may object that there is no scope for competition assessments in this regulated domain of activity. However, the jurisprudence of the Court of Justice of the EU indicates that where regulation leaves scope for discretion, there is scope for the application of the competition rules. It is in these grey areas of the regulatory framework that dominant firms are capitalising[39], rendering the additional oversight by competition and consumer protection authorities indispensable.
Conclusion
  1. We are encouraged that the CMA has initiated this study, and believe that a market investigation is needed. We commend the CMA for its work so far, and are eager to support it in its future deliberations on this topic.
Faithfully
Dr Johnny Ryan FRHistS Dr Orla Lynksey
submitted by CryptoJennie to BATProject